Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by...

29
Regression and Causality II Pablo Bal´ an GOV 1263, February 21 2018 Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT)

Transcript of Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by...

Page 1: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Regression and Causality II

Pablo Balan

GOV 1263, February 21 2018

Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT)

Page 2: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Housekeeping

Assignment #1: Due 7 minutes ago. Will return it to you nextThursday at the latest. Don’t be � if you get a “revise and resubmit”

Assignment #2: Due March 8

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 2 / 1

Page 3: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

The menu

Bad control

Basics of regression discontinuity designs (RDD)

Intro to R

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 3 / 1

Page 4: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Review

{Y0,Y1} |= D

{Y0,Y1} |= D|X

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 4 / 1

Page 5: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

BAD CONTROL

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 5 / 1

Page 6: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Recall the Conroy-Kurtz experiment

How can we test the informational role of ethnicity in elections?

We could assess whether its predictive power to explain votingdecisions decays when accounting for voter information about eachcandidates.

In regression terms, is β′ < β?

Votei ,c = α + βCoethnici ,c + εi ,c (1)

Votei ,c = α + β′Coethnici ,c + γKnowledgei ,c + εi ,c (2)

However, co-ethnicity might be correlated with the extent to which avoter has information about a candidate.

We cannot control for part of the role of ethnicity (information abouta candidate) that we are trying to assess!

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 6 / 1

Page 7: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Bad control

Bad control is subtle , very subtle

More isn’t always better

Can generate bias (aka post-treatment bias)

Example: you want to study the effect of schooling on income, butyou control for occupation

Denote W an indicator for a white collar job. W = 1 if white collar.W = 0 otherwise

Problem: White collar occupation (W) is affected by college (C)

Lecture example: ethnicity affects knowledge about a candidate

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 7 / 1

Page 8: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Bad control

Assume college is randomly assigned

Potential income is independent of college: {Y1,Y0 |= C}Potential occupation is independent of college: {W1,W0 |= C}Realized income is a function of college: Y = CY1 + (1− C )Y0

Realized occupation is a function of college: W = CW1 + (1− C )W0

The causal effect of college on income:

E[Y |C = 1]− E[Y |C = 0] = (R.A.) E[Y1 − Y0]

The causal effect of college on occupation:

E[W |C = 1]− E[W |C = 0] = (R.A.) E[W1 −W0]

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 8 / 1

Page 9: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Bad control

The effect of college, only for white collar workers (W = 1):

E[Y |W = 1,C = 1]− E[Y |W = 1,C = 0]

Potential outcomes (by the “linking equation”):

E[Y1|W1 = 1,C = 1]− E[Y0|W0 = 1,C = 0]

Remember: {Y1,Y0 |= C} and {W1,W0 |= C}Independence means we can get rid of C

E[Y1|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W0 = 1]

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 9 / 1

Page 10: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Bad control

E[Y1|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W0 = 1]

Same old trick: add zero

E[Y1|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W0 = 1] + E[Y0|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W1 = 1]

Rearranging, you get your good old friend:

E[Y1|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W1 = 1]︸ ︷︷ ︸Causal Efect (TOT)

+E[Y0|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W0 = 1]︸ ︷︷ ︸Selection Bias

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 10 / 1

Page 11: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Interpretation of bias term

E[Y1|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W1 = 1]︸ ︷︷ ︸Causal Efect (TOT)

+E[Y0|W1 = 1]− E[Y0|W0 = 1]︸ ︷︷ ︸Selection Bias

First term: Expected potential non-college earnings, given thatpotential white collar status associated with college education is equalto 1.

Second term: Expected potential non-college earnings, given thatpotential white collar status associated with non-college education isequal to 1

If, despite no college education, you get a white collar job, you areprobably special (have a high Y0).

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 11 / 1

Page 12: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Bad control

Potential occ and potential earnings are unobserved. We only observe the last twocolumns

Temptation: compare people with and without college, conditional on occ.

For white collar:

The ones without college must be AW (3000). They are W, regardless.

The ones with college are a mix of AW (3500) and BW (2000). Average of thetwo is 3000.

I incorrectly conclude that the effect of college on income is zero.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 12 / 1

Page 13: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Graphic intuition (from lecture)

How do results change if we account for differences in knowledge?

Y

NN

Y

= Effect of ethnicity accounting for differences

in knowledge

Y Y

N N

‐‐

( )( )+

Differences in knowledge are likely to be a result (endogenous to)ethnicity.

Voters are more likely to know about co-ethnic candidates.

We cannot control for part of the role of ethnicity (information abouta candidate) that we are trying to assess!

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 13 / 1

Page 14: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Take-away

Controlling for some variables can make things even worse

You don’t want to control for variables that are affected by thetreatment

It will bias your result (multicolinearity will just decrease precision)

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 14 / 1

Page 15: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

No easy choice

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 15 / 1

Page 16: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

REGRESSION DISCONTINUITY DESIGNS

(RDD)

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 16 / 1

Page 17: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Timing of the treatment phase-in

446 THOMAS FUJIWARA

FIGURE 4.—Timeline of electronic voting’s introduction.

3.2. Estimation Framework

3.2.1. Specification

The empirical strategy exploits the pattern of EV across states and time.As discussed in Section 2.2, in the 1994 election only paper ballots were used,while in the 1998 election only municipalities with more than 40,500 registeredvoters used EV. In 2002 only the new technology was used. To facilitate refer-encing, I denote the 1994, 1998, and 2002 elections as the “paper-only,” “dis-continuity,” and “electronic-only” elections, respectively. Figure 4 presents thistimeline graphically, as well as the timing of different legislative terms, whichare the four-year periods during which a state legislature holds office. Notethat elections are always held in October, with the elected legislature takingoffice on the first day of the following year.41

Let Si denote the share of voters in state i that reside in municipalities abovethe cutoff in the 1998 election. Since 1994 was a paper-only election, Si equalsthe share of voters in state i that changed from using paper ballots to EV be-tween the 1994 and 1998 elections. Since the 2002 election was electronic-only,the change in the share of voters using EV between 1998 and 2002 electionsequals 1−Si. Formally, let electroie denote the share of voters using EV in statei at an election held at year e. Hence:

electroi1998 − electroi1994 = Si�(4)

electroi2002 − electroi1998 = 1 − Si�(5)

This implies that a time-invariant cross-sectional variable, Si, is positively re-lated to changes in EV use in a period and negatively related to it in the follow-ing period. Hence, if a particular outcome of interest (such as health care fund-ing, utilization, and outcomes) follows this same pattern, this is interpreted asevidence of a likely causal effect of EV. The essence of the argument is that itis unlikely that an omitted variable (or measurement error) would follow thissame pattern.

41For example, the election in October 1994 selected all the legislators that held office fromJanuary 1st, 1995 to December 31st, 1998. The dates are the same for all states, and all seats of alegislature are elected and inaugurated simultaneously.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 17 / 1

Page 18: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Data and estimation

The treatment effect of a switch from paper ballots to EV onoutcome ym in municipality m is given by

β = limvm→+40,500

E [ym|vm]− limvm→→−40,500

E [ym|vm]

where vm is the number of registered voters.

β is estimated using various regression discontinuity design (RDD)techniques.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 18 / 1

Page 19: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

RD basics

Paradoxical idea: Rules (in principle the opposite of randomness)create useful experimentsSome rules are arbitrary. They provide good experiments.RD design: Treatment status is a deterministic and discontinuousfunction of a variable (running variable)

Di =

{1 if x1 ≥ x0

0 if x1 < x0

Di is a deterministic function of x : once we know xi , we know Di

Di is a discontinuous, because no matter how close x1 gets to x0,treatment is unchanged until x1 = x0

Question: How is this different from other control strategies?Can’t rely on the CIA! Can’t do T-C comparisons conditional oncovariates, because there is no value of x for which we observe bothT and C observations!

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 19 / 1

Page 20: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

RD Examples

1 Scholarships assigned only above a certain SAT score

2 Close elections

3 Stuff given to cities only above a certain population threshold (as inthe Fujiwara paper)

Basic intuition: Around the cutoff, treatment is as-if random.Observations on the other side of the cutoff are a valid counterfactualof the treated.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 20 / 1

Page 21: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Identification

What kind of causal effect is RD identifying?

τRD = E[Y1 − Y0|X = c] (Local average treatmetn effect at thethreshold)

Identified as: τRD == limx→+c E [Y |X ]− limx→−c E [Y |X ]

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 21 / 1

Page 22: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

RD failure

RD fails when:

Many things “jump” at the discontinuity, apart from the treatment

People manipulate rules (sorting)

We can:

Balance checks: variables do not “jump” at the threshold

Show that if we pick another (placebo) cutoff, the discontinuitydisappears

Show that treatment has no effect on other (placebo) outcomes

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 22 / 1

Page 23: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Fujiwara (2015)

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 23 / 1

Page 24: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Very transparent analysis!

Changes in outcomes between 1994 and 1998 as a function of thestate share of voters affected by the EV should be reversed between1998 and 2002.

VOTING TECHNOLOGY 435

FIGURE 2.—Valid votes/turnout—local averages and parametric fit. Each marker representsthe average value of the variable in a 4000-voter bin. The continuous lines are from a quadraticfit over the original (“unbinned”) data. The vertical line marks the 40,500-voter threshold.

FIGURE 3.—Registration and turnout—local averages and parametric fit.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 24 / 1

Page 25: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Did EV lead to a change in policy? (Cont.)

The de facto enfranchisement of approximately a tenth of Brazilianvoters

Increased the share of state’ budgets spent on health care by 3.4 pp,raising expenditure by 34%.Boosted the proportion of uneducated mothers with more than sevenprenatal visits by 7 pp, raising visits by 19%.Lowered the prevalence of low-weight births by 0.5 pp, decreasingincidence by 6.8%.

Various robustness checks to deal with possible concerns.

Looks at effects on municipal health care expenditures, which shouldnot have been affected since 1998 elections were only for state officials.Focuses on outcomes of literate mothers.Conducts placebo well-before and after the EV-implementation period.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 25 / 1

Page 26: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Results on health outcomesVOTING TECHNOLOGY 451

TABLE IV

MAIN OUTCOMES AND THE SIGN-SWITCH PATTERNa

Linear Combinations

Parameter: θ98 θ02 (θ98 − θ02)/2 (θ98 + θ02)/2Sample (Terms): 1994–1998 1998–2002

(Paper–Disc.) (Disc.–Electr.)Sample Avg. (1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A: Electoral OutcomesValid Votes/Turnout 0�829 0�092 −0�111 0�102 −0�009

[0�112] (0�033) (0�010) (0�017) (0�018){0�102} {0�002} {0�008} {0�630}

Seat-Weighted 4�623 −0�112 0�299 −0�206 0�094Policy Position [0�601] (0�641) (0�167) (0�350) (0�302)

{0�842} {0�154} {0�574} {0�800}Panel B: Fiscal Outcomes (Health Care Spending)log(Total Spending) — −0�004 −0�257 0�127 −0�131

(0�093) (0�156) (0�097) (0�082){0�946} {0�274} {0�254} {0�228}

Share of Spending 0�099 0�039 −0�029 0�034 0�005in Health Care [0�037] (0�017) (0�013) (0�008) (0�013)

{0�104} {0�044} {0�000} {0�678}log(Health — 0�428 −0�677 0�552 −0�125

Spending p.c.) (0�264) (0�262) (0�096) (0�242){0�200} {0�034} {0�000} {0�628}

Panel C: Birth Outcomes (Mothers Without Primary Schooling)Share With 7+ Visits 0�362 0�122 −0�023 0�069 0�047

[0�123] (0�065) (0�033) (0�040) (0�039){0�154} {0�558} {0�182} {0�320}

Share With Low-Weight 7�721 −0�370 0�528 −0�529 0�201Births (×100) [1�110] (0�304) (0�269) (0�246) (0�236)

{0�266} {0�104} {0�044} {0�450}N (State-Terms) — 54 54 — —N (States/First-Diffs) — 27 27 — —

aStandard errors clustered at the state level in parentheses. Standard deviations in brackets. p-values based onCameron, Gelbach, and Miller (2008) cluster-robust wild-bootstrap in curly brackets—{}. The unit of observation is astate-electoral term. Each row reports the estimation of equations (6) and (7) using the specified dependent variable.Each figure in columns (1) and (2) is from a separate regression, providing the coefficient on the share of voters livingabove the cutoff (Si) on the 1998 and 2002 first-differences, respectively (θ98 and θ02). Columns (3) and (4) reportthe specified linear combination of these parameters. Region-time effects are included.

the RDD studied in Section 2, allowing a comparison between the two em-pirical strategies. The estimated θ98 and θ02 are 9.2 p.p. and −11�1 p.p., re-spectively. This indicates that states with a larger share of their populationliving above the cutoff experienced faster growth in valid votes in the 1994and 1998 elections, but slower growth between the 1998 and 2002 elections.Column (3) presents an estimate of the average implied effect of EV by pro-

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 26 / 1

Page 27: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Placebo

No effect on municipal health care expenditures.

VOTING TECHNOLOGY 457

TABLE V

PLACEBO TESTSa

Linear Combinations

Parameter: θ98 θ02 (θ98 − θ02)/2 (θ98 + θ02)/2Sample (Terms): 1994–1998 1998–2002

(Paper–Disc.) (Disc.–Electr.)Sample Avg. (1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A: Effects on CovariatesShare of Spending 0�096 −0�011 −0�016 0�003 −0�013

in Health Care— [0�048] (0�021) (0�014) (0�015) (0�009)Municipalities {0�714} {0�296} {0�932} {0�244}

log(Population) — 0�064 0�059 0�002 0�062(0�032) (0�026) (0�015) (0�025){0�158} {0�088} {0�886} {0�088}

log(GDP) — 0�007 0�096 −0�051 0�044(0�053) (0�202) (0�088) (0�117){0�920} {0�626} {0�630} {0�680}

Poverty Rate 0�397 0�080 0�105 −0�012 0�093[0�164] (0�045) (0�024) (0�019) (0�031)

{0�144} {0�014} {0�676} {0�032}Gini Index 0�569 0�034 0�042 −0�004 0�038

[0�034] (0�031) (0�009) (0�014) (0�017){0�330} {0�000} {0�804} {0�106}

Panel B: Birth Outcomes for Mothers Who Completed Primary SchoolingShare With 7+ Visits 0�569 0�062 0�009 0�031 0�039

[0�127] (0�036) (0�022) (0�019) (0�026){0�152} {0�742} {0�134} {0�182}

Share With Low-Weight 6�261 0�391 −0�023 0�196 0�178Births (×100) [1�581] (0�474) (0�550) (0�502) (0�130)

{0�398} {0�900} {0�626} {0�208}Panel C: Pre- and Post-Trend Analysis: “Effect” in Periods Without Change in Voting Technology

Parameter: θ94 θ06 (θ94 − θ06)/2 (θ94 + θ06)/2Sample (Terms): 1990–1994 2002–2006

(Paper–Paper) (Electr.–Electr.)

Share of Spending — −0�006 −0�005 −0�0003 −0�006in Health Care (0�026) (0�013) (0�014) (0�014)

{0�884} {0�756} — —

N (State-Terms) 54 54 — —N (States/First-Diffs) 27 27 — —

aSee Table IV notes.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 27 / 1

Page 28: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

Placebo (Cont.)

No effect for educated mothers or in other periods.

VOTING TECHNOLOGY 457

TABLE V

PLACEBO TESTSa

Linear Combinations

Parameter: θ98 θ02 (θ98 − θ02)/2 (θ98 + θ02)/2Sample (Terms): 1994–1998 1998–2002

(Paper–Disc.) (Disc.–Electr.)Sample Avg. (1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A: Effects on CovariatesShare of Spending 0�096 −0�011 −0�016 0�003 −0�013

in Health Care— [0�048] (0�021) (0�014) (0�015) (0�009)Municipalities {0�714} {0�296} {0�932} {0�244}

log(Population) — 0�064 0�059 0�002 0�062(0�032) (0�026) (0�015) (0�025){0�158} {0�088} {0�886} {0�088}

log(GDP) — 0�007 0�096 −0�051 0�044(0�053) (0�202) (0�088) (0�117){0�920} {0�626} {0�630} {0�680}

Poverty Rate 0�397 0�080 0�105 −0�012 0�093[0�164] (0�045) (0�024) (0�019) (0�031)

{0�144} {0�014} {0�676} {0�032}Gini Index 0�569 0�034 0�042 −0�004 0�038

[0�034] (0�031) (0�009) (0�014) (0�017){0�330} {0�000} {0�804} {0�106}

Panel B: Birth Outcomes for Mothers Who Completed Primary SchoolingShare With 7+ Visits 0�569 0�062 0�009 0�031 0�039

[0�127] (0�036) (0�022) (0�019) (0�026){0�152} {0�742} {0�134} {0�182}

Share With Low-Weight 6�261 0�391 −0�023 0�196 0�178Births (×100) [1�581] (0�474) (0�550) (0�502) (0�130)

{0�398} {0�900} {0�626} {0�208}Panel C: Pre- and Post-Trend Analysis: “Effect” in Periods Without Change in Voting Technology

Parameter: θ94 θ06 (θ94 − θ06)/2 (θ94 + θ06)/2Sample (Terms): 1990–1994 2002–2006

(Paper–Paper) (Electr.–Electr.)

Share of Spending — −0�006 −0�005 −0�0003 −0�006in Health Care (0�026) (0�013) (0�014) (0�014)

{0�884} {0�756} — —

N (State-Terms) 54 54 — —N (States/First-Diffs) 27 27 — —

aSee Table IV notes.

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 28 / 1

Page 29: Regression and Causality II - Harvard University · 2018-03-04 · Some slides draw on slides by Joshua Angrist (MIT), Gary King (Harvard) and Teppei Yamamoto (MIT) Housekeeping Assignment

R!

Pablo Balan Regression and Causality GOV 1263, February 21 2018 29 / 1