Lec3_profit Function (2)

7
PROFIT FUNCTION By definition, profit function π (p) = max py such that y is in Y  Note that the objective function is a linear function of prices Properties of Profit Function 1) Nondecreasing in output prices, noni ncreasing in input prices. If i i p  p  for all outputs and  j  j p  p  for all inputs, then π (p) π (p) Proof. Let π (p) = py and π (p) = py, by definition of π (p) pyp y Since i i p  p  for all y i 0 and i i p  p  for all y i 0 py py Hence, π (p) = pypy = π (p) 2) Homogeneous of degree 1 in p, π (t p) = t π (p) for all t 0 Proof. Let y be profit-maximising net output vector at p, so that py pyfor all yin Y. It follows that for t 0, t py t pyfor all yin Y. Hence, y also maximize profit at price t p π (t p) = t py = t π (p) 3) Convex in p. π (t p + (1- t )p) t π (p) + (1- t )π (p) Proof. Let p′′ = t p + (1- t )pand y, yand y′′ maximise profits at p, pand p′′ respectively, then π (t p + (1- t )py) = (t p + (1- t )p) y′′= t py′′ + (1- t )py′′ 1

Transcript of Lec3_profit Function (2)

8/8/2019 Lec3_profit Function (2)

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/lec3profit-function-2 1/7

PROFIT FUNCTION

By definition, profit functionπ (p ) = max py

such that y is in Y

Note that the objective function is a linear function of prices

Properties of Profit Function

1) Nondecreasing in output prices, nonincreasing in input prices.If ii p p ≥′ for all outputs and j j p p ≤′ for all inputs, thenπ (p′ ) ≥ π (p )

Proof.Let π (p ) = py and π (p′ ) = p′y′ , by definition of π (p ) → p′y′ ≥ p′ySince ii p p ≥′ for all yi ≥ 0 and ii p p ≤′ for all yi ≤ 0 → p′y ≥ pyHence, π (p′ ) = p′y′ ≥ py = π (p )

2) Homogeneous of degree 1 in p , π (t p ) = t π (p ) for all t ≥0

Proof.Let y be profit-maximising net output vector at p , so that py ≥ py′for all y′ in Y . It follows that for t ≥0, t py ≥ t py′ for all y′ in Y .Hence, y also maximize profit at price t p → π (t p ) = t py = t π (p )

3) Convex in p . π (t p + (1- t )p′ ) ≤ t π (p ) + (1- t )π (p′ )

Proof.Let p′′ = t p + (1- t )p′ and y, y′ and y′′ maximise profits at p , p′and p′′ respectively, then

π (t p + (1- t )p′y ) = ( t p + (1- t )p′ ) y′′= t py′′ + (1- t )p′y′′

1

8/8/2019 Lec3_profit Function (2)

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/lec3profit-function-2 2/7

By definition of profit maximization we havet py′′ ≤ t py = t π (p ) and (1- t )p′y′′ ≤ (1- t )p′y′ = (1- t )π (p′ )

Hence, π (t p + (1- t )p′y ) ≤ t π (p ) + (1- t )π (p′ )

Example: The effect of price stabilizationThink of t as the probability that price of output is p and (1- t ) the

probability that the price is p′ .Then, by convexity, the average profits with a fluctuating price areat least as large as with a stabilized price.

4) Continuous in p at least when π (p ) is well-defined and p i > 0

for i = 1, 2, …n Note: An expression is called "well defined" if its definition assigns it aunique interpretation or value.

Supply and demand functions from the profit function

Note that given a net supply function y(p) , π (p ) = py (p )(can find π (p ) from y(p ))

Hotelling’s lemma

Let yi(p ) be the firm’s net supply function for good i, then

yi(p ) =( )

i p∂∂ pπ

for i = 1, 2, …n

assuming that the derivative exists and that p i > 0

Alternatively, if y ( p, w) is the supply function and x ( p, w) is thefactor demand function, then

y ( p ,w ) =( ) p p

∂ w,π

- xi( p ,w ) =( )

iw p

∂∂ w,π

for all input i

2

8/8/2019 Lec3_profit Function (2)

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/lec3profit-function-2 3/7

IntuitionWhen output price changes by a small amount

-Direct effect: because of the price increase, the firm will makemore profits even at the same level of output

-Indirect effect: a small increase in output price will induce firms tochange output level by a small amount. But the change in profit asoutput changes by a small amount must be 0 from condition for

profit-maximising production plans

To see this consider a case with one output and one input

π ( p, w) = pf ( x( p, w)) − wx( p, w)

Differentiate w.r.t p i

i pw p

∂∂ ),(π

= pw p x

w p

w p x x

w p x f pw p x f

∂−

∂+ ),(),()),((

)),((

=

pw p x

w x

w p x f pw p y ∂

∂−∂

∂+ ),()),((),(

However, 0)),(( =−

∂∂

w x

w p x f p from F.O.C.

Hence,i p

w p∂

∂ ),(π

= ),( w p y

Similarly for x

3

8/8/2019 Lec3_profit Function (2)

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/lec3profit-function-2 4/7

The Envelope Theorem

Consider an arbitrary maximization problemM (a) = ( )a x f

x,max

Let x(a) be the value of x that solves the maximization problem,then we can write

M (a) = f ( x(a), a)

The optimized value of the function is equal to the functionevaluated at optimizing choice.

By the Envelope Theorem ,

)(),()(

a x xaa x f

daadM

=∂∂=

The derivative of M w.r.t. a is given by the partial derivative of theobjective function w.r.t. a , holding x fixed at the optimal choice.

Proof.Differentiate M (a) w.r.t. a

aaa x f

aa x

xaa x f

daadM

∂∂+

∂∂

∂∂= )),(()()),(()(

Note that since x(a) maximizes f , then 0)),(( =∂∂ xaa x f

Example : one-output and one-input profit maximization problem

π ( p, w) = xmax pf ( x) − wx

According to the envelope theorem

),(),(

)),(()(),(

),(

),(

w p x xw

w p

w p x f x f p

w p

w p x x

w p x x

−=−=∂∂

==∂

=

=

π

π

Comparative statics using the profit function

1) The profit function is monotonic in prices.

4

8/8/2019 Lec3_profit Function (2)

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/lec3profit-function-2 5/7

( )i p∂

∂ pπ

> 0 if good i is an output, i.e. yi > 0( )

i p∂∂ pπ

< 0 if good i is an input, i.e. yi < 0

2) The profit function is homogenous of degree 1 in the prices.

This implies that the partial derivative( )

i p∂∂ pπ

= yi(p ) is

homogenous of degree zero. (see previous proof for 2))

3) The profit function is a convex function of p .

Hence the Hessian matrix must be positive semidefinite.

Together with Hotelling’s lemma, we have

∂∂

∂∂

∂∂

∂∂

=

∂∂

∂∂∂

∂∂∂

∂∂

2

2

1

2

2

1

1

1

22

2

12

221

2

21

2

p y

p y

p y

p y

p p p

p p pπ π

π π

The matrix on the left is the Hessian matrix

The matrix on the right is called the substitution matrix , itshows how the net supply of good i changes as the price of good j changes.

5

8/8/2019 Lec3_profit Function (2)

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/lec3profit-function-2 6/7

Example: The LeChatelier principle

For simplicity, assume that there is a single output and all input prices, w , are all fixed.Hence profit function = π ( p)

Denote the short-run profit function by π S( p,z )where z is some factor that is fixed in the short run.

Let the long-run profit-maximizing demand for this factor be given by z ( p),so that the long-run profit function is given by π L( p) = π S( p,z ( p))

Let p* be some given output price, and let z*=z ( p* ) be the optimallong-run demand for the factor at price p*

The long-run profits are always at least as large as the short-run profits

h( p) = π L( p) − π S( p,z *) = π S( p,z ( p)) − π S( p,z *) ≥ 0

for all prices p

At price p* , h( p) reaches the minimum (=0), hence 0*)( =

dp pdh

This implies that 0*)*,(*)( =

∂∂−

∂∂

p

z p

p

p S L π π

i) By Hotelling’s lemma, y L ( p*) = y S ( p* , z *)

In addition, since p* is the minimum of h( p), the second derivative

of h( p) must be nonnegative, 0*)*,(*)(

2

2

2

2≥

∂∂−

∂∂

p

z p

p

p S L π π

6

8/8/2019 Lec3_profit Function (2)

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/lec3profit-function-2 7/7

ii) By Hotelling’s lemma,

0*)*,(*)(*)*,(*)(

2

2

2

2≥

∂∂−

∂∂=

∂∂−

∂∂

p

z p

p

p p

z p y p p y S LS L π π

The long-run supply response to a change in price is at least aslarge as the short-run supply response at z*=z ( p* )

7