atanasiu

download atanasiu

of 6

Transcript of atanasiu

  • 8/12/2019 atanasiu

    1/6

    Informatica Economic, nr. 2 (42)/2007126

    More General Credibility Models

    Virginia ATANASIUDepartment of Mathematics, Academy of Economic Studies

    e-mail: [email protected]

    This communication gives some extensions of the original Bhlmann model. The paper

    is devoted to semi-linear credibility, where one examines functions of the random variables

    representing claim amounts, rather than the claim amounts themselves. The main purpose of

    semi-linear credibility theory is the estimation of ( ) ( )[ ] 100 += tXfE (the net premium fora contract with risk parameter: ) by a linear combination of given functions of the observ-

    able variables: ( tXXXX ,...,, 21'

    = ). So the estimators mainly considered here are linearfunctions of several functions of the observable random variables. The approxi-

    mation to

    nfff ,...,, 21( )0 based on prescribed approximating functions leads to the opti-

    mal non-homogeneous linearized estimator for the semi-linear credibility model. Also we dis-

    cuss the case when taking for all:

    nfff ,...,, 21

    ffp = p, try to find the optimal function . It should be

    noted that the approximation to

    f

    ( )0 based on a unique optimal approximating functionis always better than the one furnished in the semi-linear credibility model based on pre-

    scribed approximating functions: . The usefulness of the latter approximation is

    that it is easy to apply, since it is sufficient to know estimates for the structural parameters

    appearing in the credibility factors. From this reason we give some unbiased estimators for

    the structure parameters. For this purpose we embed the contract in a collective of contracts,

    all providing independent information on the structure distribution. We close this paper bygiving the semi-linear hierarchical model used in the applications chapter.

    f

    nfff ,...,, 21

    Mathematics Subject Classification: 62P05.Keywords: contracts, unbiased estimators, structure parameters, several approximating func-

    tions, semi-linear credibility theory, unique optimal function, parameter estimation, hierar-

    chical semi-linear credibility theory.

    ntroduction

    Incredi

    this article we first give the semi-linearbility model (see Section 1), which in-

    volves only one isolated contract. Our prob-lem (from Section1) is the estimation of

    ( ) ( )[ ] 100 += tXfE (the net premium for acontract with risk parameter:

    ( )tXXXX ,...,, 21'

    = . So our problem (from

    Section 1) is the determination of the linearcombination of 1 and the random variables:

    ( )rp Xf , np ,1= , tr ,1= closest to( ) ( )[ ] 100 += tXfE in the least squares

    sense, where is the structure variable. Thesolution of this problem:

    ) by a linearcombination of given functions

    of the observable variables:nfff ,...,, 21

    ( ) ( )

    = =

    2

    1 100

    ,0

    n

    p

    t

    r

    rppr XfEMin

    , where:rppr ,

    = ,

    is the optimal non-homogeneous linearized

    estimator (namely the semi-linear credibilityresult). In Section 2 we discuss the casewhen taking for all:ffp = p , try to find

    the unique optimal function . It should be

    noted that the approximation to

    I

    f

    ( )0

    f

    basedon a unique optimal approximating function

    is always better than the one furnished in

  • 8/12/2019 atanasiu

    2/6

    Informatica Economic, nr. 2 (42)/2007 127

    the semi-linear credibility model based onprescribed approximating functions:

    . The usefulness of the latter ap-

    proximation is that it is easy to apply, since it

    is sufficient to know estimates for the struc-tural parameters: , (with

    nfff ,...,, 21

    pqa pqb p ,

    q n,0= ) appearing in the credibility factors

    (wherepz np ,1= ). To obtain estimates for

    these structure parameters from the semi-linear credibility model, in Section 3we em-

    bed the contract in a collective of contracts,all providing independent information on thestructure distribution. We close this paper by

    giving the semi-linear hierarchical modelused in the applications chapter (see Section4).

    Section 1 (The approximation to ( )0 based on prescribed approximating func-

    tions: )nfff ,...,, 21

    In this section, we consider one contract withunknown and fixed risk parameter: , duringa period of t years. The yearly claim

    amounts are denoted by: . The risk

    parameter

    tXX ,...,1 is supposed to be drawn from

    some structure distribution function: ( )U . Itis assumed that, for given: , the claims areconditionally independent and identically dis-tributed (conditionally i.i.d.) with known

    common distribution function ( )

    ,xFX

    . The

    random variables are observable,

    and the random variable is considered

    as being not (yet) observable. We assume

    that:

    tXX ,...,1

    1+tX

    ( )rp Xf , np ,0= , 1,1 += tr have finitevariance. For: , we take the function of

    we want to forecast.0f

    1+tX

    We use the notation:( ) ( ) |rpp XfE= (1.1)

    1,1;,0 +== trnp

    This expression does not depend on r.We define the following structure parameters:

    ( ) ( ) ( )rprppp XfEXfEEEm === | (1.2),

    ( ) ( ) |, rqrppq XfXfCovEa = (1.3),

    ( ) ( ) qppq Covb ,= (1.4),

    ( ) ( )rqrppq XfXfCovc ,= (1.5),

    ( ) ( )qrppq XfCovd ,= (1.6),

    for: ,p nq ,0= 1,1 += tr . These expres-

    sions do not depend on: 1,1 += tr . Thestructure parameters are connected by the fol-lowing relations:

    pqpqpq bac += (1.7),

    pqpq bd = (1.8),

    for: nqp ,0, = . This follows from the covari-

    ance relations obtained in the probability the-ory where they are very well-known. Just asin the case of considering linear combina-tions of the observable variables themselves,

    we can also obtain non-homogeneous credi-bility estimates, taking as estimators the class

    of linear combinations of given functions ofthe observable variables, as shown in the fol-lowing theorem:Theorem 1.1(Optimal non-homogeneous lin-earized estimators)The linear combination of 1 and the random

    variables ( ) trnpXf rp ,1;,1, == closest to

    ( ) ( )[ ] |100 += tXfE and to ( )10 +tXf inthe least squares sense equals:

    ( ) == =

    +=n

    p

    pp

    n

    p

    t

    r

    rpp mzmXft

    zM1

    01 1

    1 (1.9),

  • 8/12/2019 atanasiu

    3/6

    Informatica Economic, nr. 2 (42)/2007128

    where is a solution to the linear system of equations:nzzz ,...,, 21

    ( )[ ] qpn

    p

    pqpq tdzdtc 01

    1 =+=

    ( nq ,1= ) (1.10)

    or to the equivalent linear system of equations:( ) qp

    n

    p

    pqpq tbztba 01

    =+=

    ( nq ,1= ) (1.11)

    Proof: we have to examine the solution of the problem:

    ( ) ( )

    = =

    2

    1 100

    ,0

    n

    p

    t

    r

    rppr XfEMin

    (1.12)

    Taking the derivative with respect to 0 gives:

    ( )[ ] ( )[ ] 01 1

    0 = = =

    rp

    n

    p

    t

    r

    pr XfEE , or: . Inserting this expression for= =

    =n

    p

    t

    r

    pprmm

    1 1

    00

    0 into (1.12) leads to the following problem:

    ( ) ( )(

    = =

    2

    1 100

    n

    p

    t

    r

    prppr mXfmEMin

    ) (1.13)

    On putting the derivatives with respect to 'qr equal to zero, we get the following system of

    equations ( nq ,1= ; tr ,1'= ):

    ( ) ( )[ ] ( ) ( )[= =

    =n

    p

    t

    r

    rqrpprrq XfXfCovXfCov1 1

    ''0 ,, ] (1.14)

    Because of the symmetry in time clearly:pptpp ==== ...21 , so using the co-

    variance results, for nq ,1= this system of

    equations can be written as:

    ( )[=

    +=n

    p

    pqpqpq dtcb1

    0 1 ] (1.15)

    Now (1.15) and (1.13) lead to (1.9) with:

    t

    zpp = , np ,1= .

    Section 2(The approximationto ( )0 based on a unique optimal approximatingfunction: )f

    The estimator for ( )0 of Theorem 1.1can be displayed as:

    ( ) ( tXfXfM ++= ...1 ) (2.1),

    where:

    ( ) ( ) == +=

    n

    ppp

    n

    ppp mztmtxfztxf 1

    01

    111

    .

    Let us forget now about this structure ofand look for any function such that (2.1)

    is closest to:

    ff

    ( )0 . If are considered only

    functions such thatf ( )1Xf has finite vari-ance, then the optimal approximating func-tion results from the following theorem:f

    Theorem 2.1 (Optimal approximating func-tion)

    ( ) ( )tXfXf ++ ...1 is closest to ( )0 and to

    ( )10 +tXf in the least squares sense, if andonly if is a solution of the equation:f( ) ( ) ( )[ ] ( )[ ] 01 120121 + XXfEXXfEtXf

    (2.2)Proof: we have to solve the following mini-mization problem:

    ( ) ( ) ( )[ ]2110 ... ttg

    XgXgXfEMin + (2.3)

    Suppose that denotes the solution to this

    problem, then we consider:

    f

    ( ) ( ) ( )XhXfXg += , with arbitrary,like in variational calculus. Let: ( )h

  • 8/12/2019 atanasiu

    4/6

    Informatica Economic, nr. 2 (42)/2007 129

    ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )[ ]{ }21110 ...... ttt XhXhXfXfXfE = + (2.4)Clearly for to be optimal,f ( ) 00' = , so for every choice of h :

    ( ) ( ) ( )[ ] ( ) ( )[{ } 0...... 1110 ] =+++ ttt XhXhXfXfXfE (2.5),

    must hold. This can be rewritten as:( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )[ ] 01 1211120 = XhXfttXhXtfXhXtfE (2.6),

    or:

    ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )[ ] ( ) ]{ }[ ] 01 1201211 =+ XXfEXXfEtXfXhE (2.7)Because this equation has to be satisfied forevery choice of the function one obtains,the expression in brackets in (2.7) must beidentical to zero, which proves (2.2).

    h

    An application of Theorem 2.1:If can only take the values

    and

    11 ,..., +tXX

    n,...,1,0 [ ]rXqXPpqr === 21 , for: q ,

    nr ,0= , then ( ) ( tXfXf ++ ...1 ) is closestto ( )0 and to ( )10 +tXf in the least squares

    sense, if and only if for nq ,0= , ( )qf is asolution of the linear system:

    ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )qr

    n

    r

    n

    r

    qr

    n

    r

    qr prfprftpqf ===

    =+0

    000

    1 (2.8)

    Indeed: ( ) ( )( )

    ( )

    =

    = =

    n

    r

    qrp

    qf

    qXP

    qfXf

    01

    1 : , nq ,0= ; ( )[ ] ( ) ( === =

    120

    12 XrXPrfXXfEn

    r

    ) ( )

    =

    =

    ==n

    r

    qr

    qrn

    r p

    prfq

    0

    0

    ; ( )[ ] ( ) ( ) ( )

    =

    ==

    ====n

    r

    qr

    qrn

    r

    n

    r p

    prfqXrXPrfXXfE

    0

    0012

    00120 .

    Inserting these expressions for: ( )1Xf ,( )[ ]12 XXfE and ( )[ 120 XXfE ] into (2.2)

    leads to (2.8).

    Section 3 (Parameter estimation)It should be noted that the approximation to

    ( )0 based on a unique optimal approxi-mating function is always better than the

    one furnished in Section 1 based on pre-

    scribed approximating functions:. The usefulness of the latter ap-

    proximation is that it is easy to apply, since itis sufficient to know estimates for the struc-

    tural parameters , (with

    f

    nfff ,...,, 21

    pqa pqb , q n,0= )

    appearing in the credibility factors (wherepz

    np ,1= ). From this reason we give some un-

    biased estimators for the structure parame-

    ters. For this purpose we consider con-

    tracts,

    k

    kj ,1= , and independent and

    identically distributed vectors

    k ( 2 )

    ( )jtjjjj XXX ,...,,, 1'

    = , for kj ,1= . The

    contract indexed j is a random vector consist-ing of a random structure parameter j and

    observations: , wherejtj XX ,...,1 kj ,1= . For

    every contract kj ,1= and for j fixed, the

    variables: are conditionally inde-

    pendent and identically distributed.jtj XX ,...,1

    Theorem 3.1 (Unbiased estimators for thestructure parameters)Let:

    = =

    ==k

    j

    jr

    t

    r

    p

    p

    p Xfkt

    Xkt

    m1 1

    ..

    ^

    )(11

    (3.1)

    =

    = =q

    j

    q

    jr

    k

    j

    t

    r

    p

    j

    p

    jrpqX

    tXX

    tX

    tka

    .1 1 .

    ^ 11

    )1(

    1 (3.2)

  • 8/12/2019 atanasiu

    5/6

    Informatica Economic, nr. 2 (42)/2007130

    t

    aX

    ktX

    tX

    ktX

    tkb

    pqqq

    j

    k

    j

    pp

    jpq

    ^

    ...1

    ...

    ^ 1111

    1

    1

    =

    =

    (3.3),

    , then: , , , where: , ,

    , , with

    pp mmE =

    ^

    pqpq aaE =

    ^

    pqpq bbE =

    ^

    ==

    t

    r

    p

    jr

    p

    j XX 1. ==

    t

    r

    q

    jr

    q

    j XX 1.

    = =

    =k

    j

    t

    r

    p

    jr

    p XX1 1

    .. = =

    =k

    j

    t

    r

    q

    jr

    q XX1 1

    .. ( )jrppjr XfX = , kj ,1( = and tr ,1= ),

    ( )jrqqjr XfX = , kj ,1( = and tr ,1= ), for p , nq ,0= , such that qp< .Proof: note that the usual definitions of the structure parameters apply, with j replacing

    and replacing so:jrX rX ( )[ ] ====

    prj

    p

    rj

    jrpp mkt

    ktm

    ktXfE

    ktmE

    ,,

    ^ 11pm ;

    ( ) ( )[ ( ) ( ) ( )

    +

    =

    qjpjrqjpjrqjrpjrrj

    q

    jr

    p

    jrpq X

    t

    EXEX

    t

    XCovXEXEXXCov

    tk

    aE ..,

    ^ 11,,

    1

    1

    ( )qjrpjqjrpj XEXt

    EXXt

    Cov

    ..

    1,

    1

    ( )

    =

    +

    +

    1

    1111,

    1....

    tkX

    tEX

    tEX

    tX

    tCov qj

    p

    j

    q

    j

    p

    j

    ( )

    +

    ++

    +

    +++

    rj

    qppqpqqppqpqqppqpqqppqpq mmbat

    mmbat

    mmbat

    mmba,

    111

    =( ) ( )

    ( )pqpq

    rj

    pqpqpqpq aat

    tkt

    tkba

    tba

    tk=

    =

    +

    1

    1

    11

    1

    1

    ,

    ;

    =

    j

    pqt

    Covk

    bE1

    1

    1^

    ,1111

    ,1111

    , ............pqp

    j

    qp

    j

    q

    j

    p

    j

    q

    j

    p

    j X

    kt

    CovX

    kt

    EX

    t

    EX

    kt

    X

    t

    CovX

    t

    EX

    t

    EX

    t

    X

    +

    =

    +

    +

    t

    aX

    ktEX

    ktEX

    ktX

    ktCovX

    tEX

    ktEX

    t

    pqqpqpq

    j

    pq

    j ............

    111,

    1111,

    1

    1

    k

    +

    +

    +

    ++

    + pqqppqpqqppqpqqp

    j

    pqpq akt

    mmbk

    akt

    mmbk

    akt

    mmbat

    111111

    =

    +

    =

    +

    +

    t

    ab

    ka

    ktba

    tkt

    ammb

    k

    pq

    pqpqpqpq

    j

    pq

    qppq

    111

    1

    11pqb

    k

    kk

    k

    1

    1

    1

    +

    pq

    pqpq

    pq

    pq

    pq bt

    a

    t

    ab

    t

    aa

    kt

    kk

    k=+=

    +

    1

    1

    1.

    Section 4(Applications of semi-linearcredibility theory)We close this paper by giving the semi-linear hierarchical modelused in the appli-cations chapter. Like in Jewells hierarchicalmodel we consider a portfolio of contracts,which can be broken up into P sectors eachsector consisting of groups of con-

    tracts. Instead of estimating: ,

    p pk

    1,, +tjpX

    jpptjpjppXE ,, 1,, += (the pure net

    risk premium of the contract ),( )jp,

    ( )ptjpp XE 1,, += (the pure net risk pre-

    mium of the sector ), we now estimate:p

    1,,0 +tjpXf ,

    ( )jpptjpjpp

    XfE ,, 1,,00 += (the pure

    net risk premium of the contract ),( )jp,

    ( ) ( )ptjpp XfE 1,,00 += (the pure net risk

    premium of the sector p ), where Pp ,1=

    and pkj ,1= . In semi-linear credibility the-

    ory the following class of estimators is con-

  • 8/12/2019 atanasiu

    6/6

    Informatica Economic, nr. 2 (42)/2007 131

    sidered: ,

    where are functions given in

    advance. Let us consider the case of onegiven function in order to approximate

    ( )qirp

    n

    p

    P

    q

    k

    i

    t

    r

    pqir Xfq

    = = = =

    +1 1 1 1

    0

    ( ) ( ) nff ,...,1

    1f

    1,,0 +tjpXf or p0 and jpp ,0 . We

    formulate the following theorem:Theorem 4.1 (Hierarchical semi-linearcredibility)Using the same notations as introduced forthe hierarchical model of Jewell and denoting

    pjspjs XfX 00 = and pjspjs XfX 1

    1 = one ob-

    tains the following least squares estimates forthe pure net risk premiums:

    ( ) ( ) 110^

    0 pzwppp Xzmzm += ,

    ( ) ( ) 110^

    0 , pjwpjpjpjp Xzmzm += (3.1)

    where: 1

    1 .

    1pjr

    t

    r pj

    pjr

    pjw Xw

    wX

    =

    = ,

    1

    1 .

    1pjw

    k

    j p

    pj

    pzw Xz

    zX

    p

    =

    = ,

    11.1101. 1/ dwcdwz pjpjpj += (the credibility factor on contract level), with:

    ( )1 '001 , pjrpjr XXCovd = , ( )1 '111 , pjrpjr XXCovd = ,'rr , ( ) ( )11111 , pjrpjrpjr XVarXXCovc == ,

    and: 11.1101. 1/ DzCDzz ppp += (the

    credibility factor at sector level), with:

    ( )1 '001 , wpjpjw XXCovD = ,( )1 '111 , wpjpjw XXCovD = , ,'jj =11C

    ( ) ( )111 , pjwpjwpjw XVarXXCov == .Remark 4.1: the linear combination of 1 and

    the random variables (1pjrX Pp ,1= ,

    pkj ,1= , tr ,1= ) closest to 1,,0 +tjpXf and

    to p0 in the least squares sense equals

    ( )p^

    0 , and the linear combination of 1 and

    the random variables (1pjrX Pp ,1= ,

    pkj ,1= , tr ,1= ) closest to jpp ,0 in

    the least squares sense equals .( )pjp ,^

    0

    References

    [1] Goovaerts, M.J., Kaas, R., VanHerwaarden, A.E., Bauwelinckx,T.:Insurance Series, volume 3, EfectiveActuarial Methods, University of Amster-dam, The Netherlands, 1991.[2] Pentikinen, T., Daykin, C.D., and Pe-sonen, M.:Practical Risk Theory for Actuar-

    ies,Universit Pierr et Marie Curie, 1990.[3] Sundt, B.:An Introduction to Non-LifeInsurance Mathematics, Veroffentlichungendes Instituts fr Versicherungswissenschaftder Universitt Mannheim Band 28 , VVWKarlsruhe, 1984.